Norbert
Elais' The Civilizing Process is an explanation of the rise of the
modern nation-state, and the process by which state formation engendered
changes in the psyches and day-to-day manners of modern citizens. In
short, his argument is that the functional complexity of post-medieval
Europe went hand-in-hand with a sublimation of man's baser instincts.
Upon first glance, the reader immediately wonders about the relevance of
findings such as "in medieval society people generally blew their noses
into their hands" (126). The dominant explanations for the rise of the
modern nation-state have usually been based in economics (Marx,
Polanyi, Moore, North & Thomas) and not in the sort of etiquette,
manners and social customs that are the key operating concepts in Elias'
work. However, Elias makes a convincing case that such customs deserve
predominant explanatory weight, being vehicles of social control that
lay the psychological groundwork for the nation-state. Such a finding
helps political scientists answer the persistent question of why Western
political institutions fail when placed into unfamiliar Third-World
social environments. Most analysts have chalked this up to unequal
economic development, but Elias would probably favor an argument
emphasizing the lack of a "civilizing" process in Third-World societies.
Such an explanation--like Putnam's reasoning in revealing Southern
Italy's "civic culture" to be bankrupt--is admittedly open to criticism
of essentialism, cultural determinism, and other postmodern
shortcomings, but at a minimum, it certainly alerts us to pertinent,
non-economic variables at work in the development-democracy
relationship.
Elias selects three comparative cases, France, England
and Germany, and performs a content analysis of medieval texts on
manners, etiquette, and the transformation of the nobility from warriors
into courtiers. These texts are the empirical evidence offered for his
key variable, pan-European courtly manners delineated by social
structure (classes and "monopolies" of power). The other key variable
(it's rather unclear which one is "dependent" on the other) is the rise
of the nation-state, which was brought about by an exogenous variable
(population growth) as well as two intervening factors: 1) the decline
of the nobility relative to national absolutism (both economically and
militarily); and 2) the rise of a money economy. Elias shows how
centrifugal forces in these societies (mainly the warrior-noble class)
resisted the "integration" of absolutism/nationhood, but that these
forces in the end were overcome by economics coupled with the
centripetal social groundwork of pan-European "civilite" and social
customs, leading to an increasingly complex interweaving of social
functions. "Society was `in transition' . . . `Simplicity' . . . had
been lost. People saw things with more differentiation" (61). "Social
control was becoming more binding . . . with the structural
transformation of society . . . a change slowly came about: the
compulsion to check one's own behaviour" (70).
The near totality of
Elias' evidence is qualitative, often selected from medieval writings
and secondhand observations. Although he means to proceed inductively
from these facts, Elias often reads like a deductive historian,
especially when positing lawlike generalizations such as "the more or
less sudden emergence of words within languages nearly always points to
changes in the lives of people themselves, particularly when the new
concepts are destined to become as central and long-lived as these"
(48). In fact, his entire thesis can be summarized with another of his
apparently deductive axioms: "The growth of units of integration and
rule is always at the same time an expression of structural changes in
society, that is to say, in human relationships" (254). Marxists, of
course, would say that such social changes are themselves dependent upon
changes in the relations of production, but Elias gives equal weight to
social causes as to economic ones. The economy is by no means
neglected in his analysis, since he gives currency, demand for property,
and population growth prime explanatory roles in his causal process
(despite the fact that there is no quantitative evidence given for these
socioeconomic correlations, unlike the analysis of the same topics by
North & Thomas). However, Marxists would surely have a fit over
Elias' assertion that the civilizing process leads to a wholesale
leveling of distinctions between social classes (430), as well as his
claim that the modern state arose out of a virtual stalemate between the
bourgeois and the nobility (327).
On the topic of state-society
relations, Elias makes the provocative argument that for the past 300
years, "monopoly rulers" (including, but not limited to, absolutist
kings) are mere functionaries, with the real power resting in the hands
of their "subjects" (271). "Control of the centralized institutions
themselves is so dispersed that it is difficult to discern clearly who
are the rulers and who are the ruled" (315). Of course, under an
instable balance of power (including today's Third World) the playing
field is presumably up for grabs between different classes and parts of
the state, but in a developed society, Elias would argue that the
internalization of "civilized" norms means that the "strong" state,
while resting on a cohesive social order, is not as autonomous from
social forces as one might think.
During the Early Modern Period, Germany was a decentralized
power which featured many states. In a learned manner, he instructs the
reader on why this had been so as compared to France. However, Elias'
most helpful contribution is his contention that the court system had
been a means through which knights and nobles developed a super-ego. As
the nobles became less powerful in time, the court system also helped
the bourgeoisie become more civilized. In time, Elias argued that all
classes (upper, middle and lower) became more civilized as more
individuals came into contact with the bourgeoisie after migrating to
the towns and cities; this process, however, was, of course, an
incredibly slow one.
Geen opmerkingen:
Een reactie posten